the atrium  
   about
   email us
   search


golden threads
   greek history
   roman history
   social history
   literature
   art and arky
   other cultures
   grammatical
   classical tradition
   faqs
   text recs
   classics profession
   alia


the atrium
   this day
   awotv
   media archive
   golden threads
   bibliotheca
   latin course
   sosii books
golden threads
preindustrial world
Date: Tue, 4 May 1993
From: David Meadows
Subject: preindustrial world

This question might have an obvious answer, but I suspect very much that different people have different `obvious answers', so here goes. Whenever one delves into social history, one always runs into different perspectives: sociological, anthropological, etc. Something which seems constant, however, is the assumption that Rome was a `preindustrial' society. This, of course, is undoubtedly true if by `industrial' we refer to the industrial revolution of a couple of centuries ago. What I want to know, however, is why this line of demarcation is considered significant. Why do we assume, for example, that people lived longer in postindustrial societies? Why are preindustrial societies ... especially ancient ones ... presented to us as if there were some sort of cultural stagnation (for want of a better world), that the lifestyle of Johannes Quintus Republicus was not so different from that of someone living in the Late Empire? Why is `industrialization' such a focal point?
Date: Tue, 4 May 1993
From: David Tandy
Subject: Re: preindustrial world

David Meadows inquires after what preindustrial is supposed to mean and why is it apparently such a common focus. I think most social and economic historians use preindustrial as a synonym for precapitalist. There are other synonyms. It's a lot like pre-literate, non-literate, illiterate, not to mention proto-literate and semi-literate: you can find all of those terms and more. To me, preindustrial means precapitalist without sounding like a Marxist. Marx of course handles this lucidly in the _Formen, die der kapitalistischen Produktion vorhergehen_, part of the _Grundrisse_. Erik Hobsbawm has a terrific introduction (in English) to the translation (mid-sixties) that is usually cited, _Pre-capitalist economic formations_. There's another word that has lots of synonyms: formation means system, structur e or institution but is used pretty much only by Marxists and wannabes. I usually use forms instead of formations so that people will not stop reading. To get back to David's question: the mistaken romance with the end of the ancien regime is also behind the persistence of the terminology. I find it interesting to contemplate, living as we do in a postindustrial world.
Date: Tue, 4 May 1993
From: David Meadows
Subject: Re: preindustrial world

David Tandy replies with at least one of the replies I expected in my query on the significance of `preindustrial' society: that it is synonymous with `precapitalist' and is a way to refer to Marxist definitions without referring specifically to Marx. This takes the thread one step further ... where do we demarcate capitalist societies? Does the concept of a capitalistic society beginwith, and therefore only postdate, Marx? Or, to bring this closer to home, were there no capitalists in the ancient world? Robert Heilbroner has recently suggested this, but in my view he is far from correct [he suggests that in Rome the aim was accumulation of wealth rather than putting such wealth to work; this is obviously erroneous and is a rather unique definition of capitalism]. I guess what I'm trying to get a handle on is whether Rome was, in fact, a capitalist society and as such, this whole artificial demarcation of economic/social development into preindustrial and postindustrial societies is a bit of a red herring (no pun intended).
Date: Tue, 4 May 1993 16:30:00
From: DONALD LATEINER
Subject: Re: preindustrial world

Sallares, The Ecology of the Ancient Greek World, Part II, Demography seems to discuss some of the methodological issues you are interested in, David.
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: Alexander Ingle
Subject: preindustrial world

On David Meadows discussion about the term pre-industrial. It seems to me that the term pre-industrial is a euphemism for pre- capitalist. It would be interesting to trace the history of this word and see if it's a response to Marxist ideas on feudal or ancient societies. I don't think it's an Adam Smith kind of word, but it could pre-date Marx. The importance of demarcating pre-industrial and industrial may harken back to a Marxist emphasis between capitalist and pre-capitalist societies. A lot of Marxist work was done describing the genesis of capitalism, that is, of industrial growing out of pre-industrial society. Volume I of Capital is largely concerned with this. Since when are ancient societies presented to us as eras of CULTURAL stagnation? Except in reference to the Late Roman Empire, I've never heard this before. The argument I'm familiar with is for or against TECHNOLOGICAL stagnation. The default view is that medieval and ancient societies stood technologically still. March Bloch and others tried to show that the European middle-ages, a pre-industrial society, was actually a period of tremendous technological innovation and more important, a period when new inventions were actually applied on a wide scale (the harness, the water-mill, etc). I think that Greco-Roman antiquity has a better claim for being called a period of technological stagnation, since inventions were only applied on a limited scale. The standard Marxist notion is that slave labor precluded the use of new technologies. However, some people have claimed that large- scale farming (which produced Xenophon's, Cato's and Varro's manuals) was actually more technologically advanced than the small-scale peasant agriculture of the times. Ellen M. Wood in her *Peasant-Citizen and Slave* does ask why we should consider classical antiquity PARTICULARLY stagnant. Her answer, incidentally, to the cause of the relative (to capitalism) technological stagnation in both the feudal and Greco-Roman periods is the peasantry, not just slave labor, which could not afford and was not interested in technological advance. I haven't read the Heilbroner (please cite) but there is nothing new in suggesting that wealth wasn't invested in the ancient world. I'm actually not sure what you or he means by "put to work," but certainly the Marxist attitude (and M.I. Finley's) is that wealth was not invested as capital. Capital is a process, not just a thing, of capitalism. Money capital (profits) MUST be reinvested so that production can be increased and so that the rate of profit continually rises. Wealth circulates through the Money-Capital- Money process. Witness the trillions of dollars of wealth that float around the world every day looking for the best investment. Capital under capitalism is production and investment for the purposes of making more money via commodities, i.e. objects made ONLY to be sold, to be turned into capital in its money-form. Sure, the Romans "put their wealth to work" by buying land (but see Finley's *Ancient Economy* pp 142ff for the difficulty in both acquiring money and land), or ships for SHORT-TERM profit but they didn't INVEST to build bigger, more productive farms for the purpose of obtaining a continually escalating return, particularly since, a) new technology couldn't (somehow) be applied to farming and b) since there was an extremely circumscribed market, mostly concentrated on luxuries. I'm not saying there wasn't production for profit, even in agriculture, but profit doesn't = capital. But come up with some examples and let's look at them. See Meyer Reinhold's article on Michael Rostovzeff (Science and Society, 1946, ? vol , pp. 361-391) for a good discussion of "modernizing" the ancient world. In any case, I don't believe that you can call Roman society capitalist in any sense of the word. But what was it?
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: David Meadows
Subject: Re: preindustrial world

Just a quick preliminary observation: This is, essentially, what Heilbroner said (it was in a series of lectures which I heard on CBC's *Ideas* ... it might have been the annual Massey lectures at the University of Toronto, in which case there will be a text version available somewhere). This viewpoint has many assumptions built into it which simply have never, save perhaps on the seventh floor of McMaster University, been seriously questioned. First of all there is the assumption that real profits for capitalistic purposes come primarily from luxury goods. This is simply not true: there was extensive trade all over the Mediterranean in the so-called Mediterranean triad and much profits could be made. Now according to this definition of capitalism, these profits must be reinvested to increase production; but a chunk of land can only produce so many bushels of wheat or amphorae of oil. The only way to increase production is to bring more land under the plough and this is essentially what is happening, for example, in Spain during the early empire. We also witness such things as olive growers building kilns on their own land so they do not have to buy amphorae from the amphora dealer ... is this not capital investment? Cannot the investment in more slaves to work those kilns be considered a capital investment? On a more urban scale ... is it not capital investment to purchase a slave, teach him a trade, then give him a shop to run for you? Then you buy another slave whom the first slave instructs and you double your production. Is that not capitalism? As for Romans not purchasing land to increase production, Pliny's letter (3.19) to Calvisius Rufus suggests that profit and increased production is indeed a motivating factor in a proposed purchase of land. He notes that the land, which adjoins a piece he already owns, could be put under one steward and the same foremen that he already has. His chief worry is having so much land in one geographical place. He goes on (Penguin translation): `But the chief point for consideration is this. The land is fertile, the soil rich and well watered, and the whole made up of fields, vineyards, and woods which produce enough to yield a steady income if not a very large one. But this natural fertility is bein exhausted by poor cultivation. The last owner on more than one occasion sold up the tenants' possessions, so that he temporarily reduced their arrears but weakened their resources for the future, and consequently their debts mounted up again. They will have to be set up and given a good type of slave, which will increase the expense; for nowhere do I emply chained slaves myself, and no one uses them there ...' This sounds very much like a capital investment project to me.
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: Les Sheridan
Subject: Capitalism/Pre-industrial

Excuse a comment from someone who is by no means an expert on this subject. But, I believe people during the times being discussed were operating under laws which prohibited usury which I understand to mean a prohibition against collecting interest on loans. Which would seem to prohibit the use of money to make money. Which would appear to be a disincentive to economic growth.
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: David Meadows
Subject: Re: Capitalism/Pre-industrial

Rather, there was a maximum legal rate of interest which could be charged. Of course, the existence of such laws only implies that higher interest was being charged -- e.g. Cod.Just. 8.32(33).2 involves a case where a woman borrowed 1000 aurei with the provision that, if she didn't pay back in a certain time, she would owe 4 times that amount. In addition, there were the so-called `maritime loans' which, if the lender, who was, in essence, providing venture capital, was willing to assume the risk of shipwreck, he or she could legally exceed the going rate of interest -- see Cod.Just. 4.6.3(2) and 4.33(4).3 for examples of women taking part in this high risk, and potentially high profit activity.
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: Abigail Ann Young
Subject: Re: preindustrial world

I have been following this discussion with interest and have a few cents worth to add..... I still think Finley's arguments do convincingly show that Roman investment and land-owning practices don't constitute rational capitalism as we now define it. As I recall, he uses Pliny as one of his examples in _The Ancient Economy_! Also, I am a little surprised that no-one has mentioned what must still be the classic discussion, however much it has been argued with and refined upon in the intervening decades: Weber discusses this in _The Protestant Ethic...._ as does (as I recall) Tawney in his introductory essay to it.
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: "Daniel P. Tompkins"
Subject: Re: preindustrial world

Well, Finley is under increasing attack for this, isn't he? (I.e. whether there was "rational capitalism" in the anicent world) I think we should pursue this topic; I'll try to dig some stuff out.
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: Patrick Rourke
Subject: Re: Capitalism/Pre-industrial

Les Sheridan: "I believe during the times being discussed [people] were operating under laws which prohibited usury..." Purchasing new tools is investment. Besides, my understanding is that no one payed any attention to usury laws anyway.
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: Bill Whitt
Subject: Re: preindustrial world

Some of you might be interested in evidence outside the classical world relating to ancient "capitalism". My field of expertise is not classics but ancient Near East in 2nd mill. BCE. It would be absurd to call ancient Near East at this time "capitalist", but there are clear examples of individuals whom we today would think of as capitalists. Clay tablet archives from across Mesopotamia and northern part of Syria provide many examples of individuals and families accumulating and reinvesting huge amounts of capital in (1) banking, (2) trade, and (3) real estate. Patronage (e.g. close ties to the king) can explain many of these cases, but there are also lots of examples of people who seemed to have made it "on their own" outside of the patronage network. Most interesting perhaps are the merchants employed by kings to trade in a foreign land. These merchants (called "tamkaru" in Akkadian) traded on the king's account as well as acting as quasi-ambassadors for their king. Generally the king gave the merchant a large sum of money and it was the merchant's job to obtain items the king wanted plus turn a profit for the king on any remaining money. These merchants also traded on their own account and some of them became fabulously wealthy doing so.
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: Patrick Rourke
Subject: Preindustrial...capitalism

As a follow up to my short message: Why must loans and interest be the only way to use money to make money? What about buying at wholesale and selling at retail? Why must economic growth be predicated upon speculation? (After all, there's more to making money than the stock market, besides the opinions of the Reaganauts)
Date: Wed, 5 May 1993
From: "John D. Muccigrosso"
Subject: Pre-industrial

Since we seem to be getting into trade as evidence for capitalism (however defined), it seems like the thoughts of Polanyi et al. (Trade and Market in the Early Empires) on the subject of trade are relevant and should be considered here. N'est-ce pas?
Date: Thu, 6 May 1993
From: David Tandy
Subject: rational capitalism

For a discussion of the absence of rational capitalism in Rome from a Weberian point of view see John R. Love, _Antiquity and Capitalism. Max Weber and the sociological foundations of Roman civilization_ (Routledge 1991).
Culled from classics.log9305
Copyright © 2001 David Meadows
this page: http://atrium-media.com/goldenthreads/preindustrialsociety.html